In decision-making theory, especially when facing uncertainty, "regret theory" has become one of the important considerations for humans to make the best decisions. Regret often occurs when the best course of action is learned after a decision has been made. This emotion is a negative emotion, and its powerful influence not only affects the individual's psychological state, but also involves social and reputation levels. Regret theory questions our decision-making processes and prompts people to consider the possibility of regret in future choices.
Regret is a strong emotion that deeply affects people when faced with choices, and is then reflected in the process of rational decision-making.
Regret theory was proposed by Graham Loomes and Robert Sugden in 1982. Its core concept is "anticipated regret", which means that when people make decisions, they predict the degree of regret they may feel in the future. This theoretical model considers the gap between the actual outcome and the best choice after future uncertainty is resolved. This gap will affect the decision-maker's utility perception, making regret a key factor in decision-making.
In many situations, people overestimate their feelings of regret, especially when they have a strong sense of control over the outcome of their choices. Regret-avoidant thinking can lead to biases in decision-making. For example, when faced with an obvious choice, many people will choose a conservative path to reduce the possibility of regret in the future.
“When making decisions, we often consider the results but ignore the possible emotional experiences in the future.”
In addition, experimental research shows that when faced with an auction or choosing a gamble, people choose the option of increasing the price because of irrational feelings of regret. When other players learn the outcome of their bids, they anticipate the regret of failure, which prompts them to increase their bids to reduce the likelihood of regret.
In experiments, one group of studies found that for some choices, people are particularly likely to overestimate the degree of regret they will feel if they fail to achieve the desired outcome. For example, commuters may predict the level of regret they will feel about missing a train when they predict it is only one minute late than when they predict it is five minutes late. However, this is not the case with real emotional experiences, as people tend to attribute missing the train to external factors rather than solely to their own choices.
The applications of regret theory are not limited to auctions and choice gambling. It can also explain many economic behaviors, such as over-investment in investment behavior. When faced with economic uncertainty, investors tend to make choices based on past experience rather than relying solely on data or models.
"Regret theory is not only a theoretical model of economics, but also a mode of thinking in our daily lives."
For example, in investment selection, investors may face the choice of stocks, bonds or currency markets. After calculation, it will be crucial to choose the option that brings the lowest regret. This means taking into account not just gains but also potential regret when speculating on future returns. Using the minimax regret method, investors can find the option closest to the best option and minimize the regret they may feel in the future.
Unknown choices are often accompanied by risks, and regret theory provides a way to help us make smarter decisions and make our choices more rational. Faced with the uncertainty of the future, are you willing to consider the possibility of regret and make a better choice?