Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where David Hobson is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by David Hobson.


Mathematical Finance | 1998

Complete Models with Stochastic Volatility

David Hobson; L. C. G. Rogers

The paper proposes an original class of models for the continuous-time price process of a financial security with nonconstant volatility. The idea is to define instantaneous volatility in terms of exponentially weighted moments of historic log-price. The instantaneous volatility is therefore driven by the same stochastic factors as the price process, so that, unlike many other models of nonconstant volatility, it is not necessary to introduce additional sources of randomness. Thus the market is complete and there are unique, preference-independent options prices. Copyright Blackwell Publishers 1998.


Finance and Stochastics | 1998

Robust hedging of the lookback option

David Hobson

Abstract. The aim of this article is to find bounds on the prices of exotic derivatives, and in particular the lookback option, in terms of the (market) prices of call options. This is achieved without making explicit assumptions about the dynamics of the price process of the underlying asset, but rather by inferring information about the potential distribution of asset prices from the call prices. Thus the bounds we obtain and the associated hedging strategies are model independent. The appeal and significance of the hedging strategies arises from their universality and robustness to model mis-specification.


Finance and Stochastics | 2005

Local martingales, bubbles and option prices

Alexander M. G. Cox; David Hobson

Abstract.In this article we are interested in option pricing in markets with bubbles. A bubble is defined to be a price process which, when discounted, is a local martingale under the risk-neutral measure but not a martingale. We give examples of bubbles both where volatility increases with the price level, and where the bubble is the result of a feedback mechanism. In a market with a bubble many standard results from the folklore become false. Put-call parity fails, the price of an American call exceeds that of a European call and call prices are no longer increasing in maturity (for a fixed strike). We show how these results must be modified in the presence of a bubble. It turns out that the option value depends critically on the definition of admissible strategy, and that the standard mathematical definition may not be consistent with the definitions used for trading.


Mathematical Finance | 2001

Robust Hedging of Barrier Options

Haydyn Brown; David Hobson; L. C. G. Rogers

This article considers the pricing and hedging of barrier options in a market in which call options are liquidly traded and can be used as hedging instruments. This use of call options means that market preferences and beliefs about the future behavior of the underlying assets are in some sense incorporated into the hedge and do not need to be specified exogenously. Thus we are able to find prices for exotic derivatives which are independent of any model for the underlying asset. For example we do not need to assume that the underlying assets follow an exponential Brownian motion. We find model‐independent upper and lower bounds on the prices of knock‐in and knock‐out puts and calls. If the market prices the barrier options outside these limits then we give simple strategies for generating profits at zero risk. Examples illustrate that the bounds we give can be fairly tight.


Archive | 2011

The Skorokhod embedding problem and model-independent bounds for option prices

David Hobson

This set of lecture notes is concerned with the following pair of ideas and concepts: 1. The Skorokhod Embedding problem (SEP) is, given a stochastic process X=(X t ) t≥0 and a measure μ on the state space of X, to find a stopping time τ such that the stopped process X τ has law μ. Most often we take the process X to be Brownian motion, and μ to be a centred probability measure. 2. The standard approach for the pricing of financial options is to postulate a model and then to calculate the price of a contingent claim as the suitably discounted, risk-neutral expectation of the payoff under that model. In practice we can observe traded option prices, but know little or nothing about the model. Hence the question arises, if we know vanilla option prices, what can we infer about the underlying model?


Mathematical Finance | 2007

THE RANGE OF TRADED OPTION PRICES

Mark H. A. Davis; David Hobson

Suppose we are given a set of prices of European call options over a finite range of strike prices and exercise times, written on a financial asset with deterministic dividends which is traded in a frictionless market with no interest rate volatility. We ask: when is there an arbitrage opportunity? We give conditions for the prices to be consistent with an arbitrage-free model (in which case the model can be realized on a finite probability space). We also give conditions for there to exist an arbitrage opportunity which can be locked in at time zero. There is also a third boundary case in which prices are recognizably misspecified, but the ability to take advantage of an arbitrage opportunity depends upon knowledge of the null sets of the model.


Quantitative Finance | 2005

Static-arbitrage upper bounds for the prices of basket options

David Hobson; Peter Laurence; Tai-Ho Wang

In this paper we investigate the possible values of basket options. Instead of postulating a model and pricing the basket option using that model, we consider the set of all models which are consistent with the observed prices of vanilla options, and, within this class, find the model for which the price of the basket option is largest. This price is an upper bound on the prices of the basket option which are consistent with no-arbitrage. In the absence of additional assumptions it is the lowest upper bound on the price of the basket option. Associated with the bound is a simple super-replicating strategy involving trading in the individual calls.


Mathematical Finance | 2012

Robust Bounds for Forward Start Options

David Hobson; Anthony Neuberger

We consider the problem of finding a model‐free upper bound on the price of a forward start straddle with payoff . The bound depends on the prices of vanilla call and put options with maturities and , but does not rely on any modeling assumptions concerning the dynamics of the underlying. The bound can be enforced by a super‐replicating strategy involving puts, calls, and a forward transaction. We find an upper bound, and a model which is consistent with and vanilla option prices for which the model‐based price of the straddle is equal to the upper bound. This proves that the bound is best possible. For lognormal marginals we show that the upper bound is at most 30% higher than the Black–Scholes price. The problem can be recast as finding the solution to a Skorokhod embedding problem with nontrivial initial law so as to maximize .


Finance and Stochastics | 2010

Comparison results for stochastic volatility models via coupling

David Hobson

The aim of this paper is to investigate the properties of stochastic volatility models, and to discuss to what extent, and with regard to which models, properties of the classical exponential Brownian motion model carry over to a stochastic volatility setting. The properties of the classical model of interest include the fact that the discounted stock price is positive for all t but converges to zero almost surely, the fact that it is a martingale but not a uniformly integrable martingale, and the fact that European option prices (with convex payoff functions) are convex in the initial stock price and increasing in volatility. We explain why these properties are significant economically, and give examples of stochastic volatility models where these properties continue to hold, and other examples where they fail.The main tool is a construction of a time-homogeneous autonomous volatility model via a time-change.


Finance and Stochastics | 2012

Model-independent hedging strategies for variance swaps

David Hobson; Martin Klimmek

A variance swap is a derivative with a path-dependent payoff which allows investors to take positions on the future variability of an asset. In the idealised setting of a continuously monitored variance swap written on an asset with continuous paths, it is well known that the variance swap payoff can be replicated exactly using a portfolio of puts and calls and a dynamic position in the asset. This fact forms the basis of the VIX contract.But what if we are in the more realistic setting where the contract is based on discrete monitoring, and the underlying asset may have jumps? We show that it is possible to derive model-independent, no-arbitrage bounds on the price of the variance swap, and corresponding sub- and super-replicating strategies. Further, we characterise the optimal bounds. The form of the hedges depends crucially on the kernel used to define the variance swap.

Collaboration


Dive into the David Hobson's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Han Feng

University of Warwick

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge