Heinz D. Kurz
University of Graz
Network
Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.
Publication
Featured researches published by Heinz D. Kurz.
Review of Political Economy | 2005
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
Abstract The paper discusses Sraffas interpretation of the classical economists and, following their lead, his elaboration of an objectivist, surplus-based theory of value and distribution. The emphasis is on the twin concepts of physical real costs and social surplus on the one hand and that of a circular flow of production on the other. In order to determine relative prices within such an analytical scheme, the tool of simultaneous equations is indispensable. It is then argued that fixed capital turned out to be a formidable obstacle: whereas the circulating part of capital allows one to entertain the idea of a material-cum-value transmigration into the product, this idea loses much of its appeal with regard to the durable part. Sraffa eventually overcame the difficulty in terms of the joint-products approach.
History of Political Economy | 2006
Christian Gehrke; Heinz D. Kurz
Among Piero Sraffa s unpublished papers is a notebook with extensive excerpts from and critical comments on three contributions of Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz: “Der Kardinalfehler der Bohm-Bawerkschen Zinstheorie” (1906), “Zur Zinstheorie. II. Entgegnung” (1907b), and “Wertrechnung und Preisrechnung im Marxschen System” (1906–7).1 The reading notes and commentaries on Bortkiewicz s three essays were mainly written between January and April 1943, with some additions in December 1945 and June 1955. It was presumably the discussion of Bortkiewicz s contributions in Paul Sweezy s Theory of Capitalist Development (1942) that brought them to Sraffa s attention, who up until then appears to have been unaware of them.2 What will perhaps come as a surprise to
Journal of The History of Economic Thought | 1993
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
The paper shows that the conventional neoclassical interpretation of von Neumanns growth model cannot be sustained. Other than in models in the tradition of Walras and Cassel, in his model there is no given ‘capital’ endowment that constrains productive capacity and provides the basis, in terms of its relative ‘scarcity’, for a determination of the interest rate. Von Neumanns model is rather fully compatible with, and has been anticipated in all relevant aspects by, authors whose contributions can be strictly located within, the classical tradition. This concerns in particular the asymmetric treatment of the distributive variables. Finally it is argued that von Neumanns model may be interpreted as containing inter alia, an answer to the ideas put forward by his fellow-mathematician Robert Remark. Both circumstantial evidence and a careful textual comparison of Remaks paper on ‘superposed price systems’ and von Neumanns analysis support this interpretation.
Archive | 1993
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
Even three decades after the publication of Piero Sraffa’s Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960) and in spite of extended discussions on the matter there does not yet exist a commonly accepted view as to the meaning of the ‘Standard commodity’ and the role it plays in Sraffa’s analysis. Moreover, it seems to be still unclear what is the relationship between this concept and Ricardo’s search for an ‘invariable measure of value’.1
Progress in Industrial Ecology, An International Journal | 2006
Heinz D. Kurz
The paper starts from the premise that nobody intends on purpose to pollute the environment, render animal species extinct, etc. And yet what nobody intends happens all the time. The present paper discusses to what extent the nonintended consequences of purposeful human activities are related to the fact that production is generally joint production, generating both goods and bads. After a brief introduction into the problems at hand with reference to major economists, the implications of the following assumptions are investigated within a simple analytical framework: (a) free disposal and the Rule of Free Goods; (b) costly disposal and the negativity of some price; (c) product-cum-process innovations that render it possible to transform bads into goods. The paper concludes with some observations on renewable and exhaustible resources.
Archive | 1998
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
With the inception of systematic economic analysis in the time of the classical economists the problem of what determines the dynamism and growth performance of the economy became a major focus of research in social sciences. Since that time it has always been felt that in order to understand the nature and causes of the wealth of nations and its growth one ought to study first and foremost the ‘causes of improvement in the productive powers of labour’, as Adam Smith put it, or the factors affecting the development of the ‘productive powers of society’, to use Karl Marx’s concept. It has also always been understood that there is an endogenous side to this process of improvement in social productivity. Reading authors such as Smith, Charles Babbage, Marx or Alfred Marshall one indeed gets the impression that there is no such thing as a purely exogenous change in productive powers. These are seen to rather depend on the actions of individuals and the impact these actions have in fostering economic growth. These actions and their ‘growth effectiveness’ are envisaged as being shaped by a variety of factors including cultural norms, social institutions, and a nation’s policy.1 In these authors’ works, technological and organisational change is portrayed consistently as being essentially endogenous. For example, in Smith’s concept of the division of labour, the pace at which capital accumulates (and thus markets expand) is singled out as the factor that is most important for the growth in labour productivity and income per capita (see Smith (1976) bk I, chs i— III; see also Negishi, 1993). The endogeneity of technological progress was also stressed in more recent times by authors such as Allyn Young and, particularly, Nicholas Kaldor, who even attempted — albeit with only limited success — to put the relationship between productivity growth and capital accumulation into algebraic form, in his so-called ‘technical progress function’. It was clear to these authors that ‘human capital’ and ‘technological knowledge’ do matter, and that improvements in the ‘skill, dexterity, and judgment with which labour is applied in any nation’ (Smith) are favourable to growth.
European Journal of The History of Economic Thought | 2010
Heinz D. Kurz
Abstract The paper discusses the analyses of technical progress, capital accumulation and income distribution elaborated by three major classical economists: Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx. The interpretation given is partly inspired by Piero Sraffas studies in his hitherto unpublished papers. It will be argued that in the classical authors we encounter a sophisticated typology of different forms of technical change and an analysis of the different effects these have. These forms can be analysed in terms of shifts of the inverse relationship between the general rate of profits and wages, or wage frontier. The emphasis will be on Adam Smiths concept of the division of labour, Ricardos analysis of the substitution of machine power for labour power, and Marxs adaptation of Ricardos argument to his own analytical framework in terms of a rising organic composition of capital.
European Journal of The History of Economic Thought | 2006
Heinz D. Kurz
Abstract The paper argues that economics is not a perfect selection mechanism that preserves each and every economic idea that is valid and useful and jettisons all ideas that are not. The teleological view of the subject cannot be sustained. Therefore the task of the history of economic thought cannot be limited to the study of the past from the present state of economics. Another important task is to study the present state of economics from the standpoint of past authors in order to see what has been gained and what lost in the course of time. The history of the subject is a treasure trove of ideas. The history of economic thought may play a useful role by preserving valuable ideas which otherwise would fall into oblivion. To foster the subject is therefore also in the interest of general economists.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization | 2003
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
Abstract The paper discusses Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen’s contribution to production theory, comparing it with the contributions of John von Neumann and Piero Sraffa and emphasizing the problem of the choice of technique. It is shown that Georgescu-Roegen’s fund–flow approach, in which fixed capital is taken to be an “immutable agent”, can be misleading and cannot address issues that are easily handled by the alternative flow–flow approach that reduces fixed capital to circulating within a joint-products framework and allows adequate treatment of the wear and tear of machines as well as the problem of capital utilization.
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics | 2000
Heinz D. Kurz; Neri Salvadori
The paper elaborates a dynamic input‐output model with exhaustible resources. Discoveries of new deposits and technical progress are set aside. It is assumed that there is a ‘backstop technology’ (based on solar energy), which implies that exhaustible resources are not indispensable in production. Given the real wage rate and the consumption pattern of profit and royalty recipients, it is then shown that the paths followed by the royalties paid to the owners of resources, the quantities produced of the different commodities, and their prices are determined once a sequence of nominal profit rates is given.