Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where Yaotang Li is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by Yaotang Li.


PLOS ONE | 2014

Evolutionary Stability in the Asymmetric Volunteer's Dilemma

JunZhou He; Rui-Wu Wang; Yaotang Li

It is often assumed that in public goods games, contributors are either strong or weak players and each individual has an equal probability of exhibiting cooperation. It is difficult to explain why the public good is produced by strong individuals in some cooperation systems, and by weak individuals in others. Viewing the asymmetric volunteers dilemma game as an evolutionary game, we find that whether the strong or the weak players produce the public good depends on the initial condition (i.e., phenotype or initial strategy of individuals). These different evolutionarily stable strategies (ESS) associated with different initial conditions, can be interpreted as the production modes of public goods of different cooperation systems. A further analysis revealed that the strong player adopts a pure strategy but mixed strategies for the weak players to produce the public good, and that the probability of volunteering by weak players decreases with increasing group size or decreasing cost-benefit ratio. Our model shows that the defection probability of a “strong” player is greater than the “weak” players in the model of Diekmann (1993). This contradicts Seltens (1980) model that public goods can only be produced by a strong player, is not an evolutionarily stable strategy, and will therefore disappear over evolutionary time. Our public good model with ESS has thus extended previous interpretations that the public good can only be produced by strong players in an asymmetric game.


Science China-life Sciences | 2010

Asymmetric interaction will facilitate the evolution of cooperation

Rui-Wu Wang; JunZhou He; Ya-Qiang Wang; Lei Shi; Yaotang Li

Explaining the evolution of cooperation remains one of the greatest problems for both biology and social science. The classical theories of cooperation suggest that cooperation equilibrium or evolutionary stable strategy between partners can be maintained through genetic similarity or reciprocity relatedness. These classical theories are based on an assumption that partners interact symmetrically with equal payoffs in a game of cooperation interaction. However, the payoff between partners is usually not equal and therefore they often interact asymmetrically in real cooperative systems. With the Hawk-Dove model, we find that the probability of cooperation between cooperative partners will depend closely on the payoff ratio. The higher the payoff ratio between recipients and cooperative actors, the greater will be the probability of cooperation interaction between involved partners. The greatest probability of conflict between cooperative partners will occur when the payoff between partners is equal. The results show that this asymmetric relationship is one of the key dynamics of the evolution of cooperation, and that pure cooperation strategy (i.e., Nash equilibrium) does not exist in asymmetrical cooperation systems, which well explains the direct conflict observed in almost all of the well documented cooperation systems. The model developed here shows that the cost-to-benefit ratio of cooperation is also negatively correlated with the probability of cooperation interaction. A smaller cost-to-benefit ratio of cooperation might be created by the limited dispersal ability or exit cost of the partners involved, and it will make the punishment of the non-cooperative individuals by the recipient more credible, and therefore make it more possible to maintain stable cooperation interaction.


Scientific Reports | 2015

Asymmetric interaction paired with a super-rational strategy might resolve the tragedy of the commons without requiring recognition or negotiation

Jun-Zhou He; Rui-Wu Wang; Christopher Jensen; Yaotang Li

Avoiding the tragedy of the commons requires that one or more individuals in a group or partnership “volunteer”, benefiting the group at a cost to themselves. Recognition and negotiation with social partners can maintain cooperation, but are often not possible. If recognition and negotiation are not always the mechanism by which cooperative partnerships avoid collective tragedies, what might explain the diverse social cooperation observed in nature? Assuming that individuals interact asymmetrically and that both “weak” and “strong” players employ a super-rational strategy, we find that tragedy of the commons can be avoided without requiring either recognition or negotiation. Whereas in the volunteers dilemma game a rational “strong” player is less likely to volunteer to provide a common good in larger groups, we show that under a wide range of conditions a super-rational “strong” player is more likely to provide a common good. These results imply that the integration of super-rationality and asymmetric interaction might have the potential to resolve the tragedy of the commons. By illuminating the conditions under which players are likely to volunteer, we shed light on the patterns of volunteerism observed in variety of well-studied cooperative social systems, and explore how societies might avert social tragedies.


Scientific Reports | 2016

Collective punishment is more effective than collective reward for promoting cooperation.

Lei Gao; Zhen Wang; Riccardo Pansini; Yaotang Li; Rui-Wu Wang

Collective punishment and reward are usually regarded as two potential mechanisms to explain the evolution of cooperation. Both scenarios, however, seem problematic to understand cooperative behavior, because they can raise the second-order free-rider problem and many organisms are not able to discriminate less cooperating individuals. Even though they have been proved to increase cooperation, there has been a debate about which one being more effective. To address this issue, we resort to the N-player evolutionary snowdrift game (NESG), where a collective punishment/reward mechanism is added by allowing some players to display punishment/reward towards all remaining players. By means of numerous simulations and analyses, we find that collective punishment is more effective in promoting cooperation for a relatively high initial frequency of cooperation or for a relatively small group. When the intensity of punishment exceeds a certain threshold, a stable state of full cooperation emerges for both small and large groups. In contrast, such state does not appear for large groups playing a NESG with reward mechanism. In the case of mutualistic interactions, finally, our results show the new payoff with collective punishment/reward can lead to the coexistence of cooperators and defectors when discrimination between these two is not possible.


PLOS ONE | 2013

Resource elasticity of offspring survival and the optimal evolution of sex ratios.

Rui-Wu Wang; Ya-Qiang Wang; JunZhou He; Yaotang Li

The fitness of any organisms includes the survival and reproductive rate of adults and the survival of their offspring. Environmental selection pressures might not affect these two aspects of an organism equally. Assuming that an organism first allocates its limited resources to maintain its survival under environmental selection pressure, our model, based on the evolutionarily stable strategy theory, surprisingly shows that the sex ratio is greatly affected by the environmental pressure intensity and by the reproductive resource elasticity of offspring survival. Moreover, the concept of the resource elasticity of offspring survival intrinsically integrates the ecological concepts of K selection and r selection. The model shows that in a species with reproductive strategy K, increased environmental selection pressure will reduce resource allocation to the male function. By contrast, in a species with reproductive strategy r, harsher environmental selection pressure will increase allocation to the male function. The elasticity of offspring survival might vary not only across species, but also across many other factors affecting the same species (e.g., age structure, spatial heterogeneity), which explains sex ratio differences across species or age structures and spatial heterogeneity in the same species.


Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics | 2016

Minimal Geršgorin tensor eigenvalue inclusion set and its approximation

Chaoqian Li; Chengyi Zhang; Yaotang Li

For a tensor, its minimal Gersgorin tensor eigenvalue inclusion set is presented. By establishing a sufficient and necessary condition for the elements belonging to this set, we give a sequence of approximation sets and prove that the limit of this sequence is the minimal Gersgorin tensor eigenvalue inclusion set for an irreducible tensor.


Scientific Reports | 2015

The shift between the Red Queen and the Red King effects in mutualisms

Lei Gao; Yaotang Li; Rui-Wu Wang

Interspecific mutualisms consist of partners trading services that yield common benefits to both species. Until now, understanding how the payoffs from mutualistic cooperation are allocated among the participants has been problematic. Two hypotheses have been proposed to resolve this problem. The Red Queen effect argues that faster-evolving species are favoured in co-evolutionary processes because they are able to obtain a larger share of benefits. Conversely, the Red King effect argues that the slower-evolving species gains a larger share of benefits. The model we propose shows that the allocations for a common benefit vary when the effect of a reward mechanism is included in the model. The outcome is a shift from the Red Queen effect to the Red King effect and vice versa. In addition, our model shows that either an asymmetry in payoff or an asymmetry in the number of cooperative partners causes a shift between the Red Queen effect and the Red King effect. Even in situations where the evolutionary rates are equal between the two species, asymmetries in rewards and in participant number lead to an uneven allocation of benefits among the partners.


Linear & Multilinear Algebra | 2018

SDB-tensors and SQB-tensors

Aiquan Jiao; Chaoqian Li; Yaotang Li

ABSTRACT In this paper, we propose four new classes of structured tensors: -tensors, -tensors, and prove that even order real symmetric SDB-tensors and SQB-tensors are positive definite, and that even order real symmetric -tensors and -tensors are positive semi-definite. These new classes of structured tensors provide two checkable sufficient conditions for the positive definite tensors and two checkable sufficient conditions for the positive semi-definite tensors.


Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics | 2018

Error bounds for linear complementarity problems of S-Nekrasov matrices and B–S-Nekrasov matrices

Lei Gao; Yaqiang Wang; Chaoqian Li; Yaotang Li

Abstract An error bound involving a parameter, which does not always work, for the linear complementarity problem (LCP) when the involved matrices are S -Nekrasov matrices is provided by M. Garcia-Esnaola and J.M. Pena (2014). In this paper, a new error bound for the LCP of S -Nekrasov matrices is presented, which depends only on the entries of the involved S -Nekrasov matrices. Based on the obtained results, we also give an error bound for the LCP of B – S -Nekrasov matrices.


Scientific Reports | 2016

Sex ratio elasticity influences the selection of sex ratio strategy

Ya-Qiang Wang; Rui-Wu Wang; Yaotang Li; Zhanshan (Sam) Ma

There are three sex ratio strategies (SRS) in nature—male-biased sex ratio, female-biased sex ratio and, equal sex ratio. It was R. A. Fisher who first explained why most species in nature display a sex ratio of ½. Consequent SRS theories such as Hamilton’s local mate competition (LMC) and Clark’s local resource competition (LRC) separately explained the observed deviations from the seemingly universal 1:1 ratio. However, to the best of our knowledge, there is not yet a unified theory that accounts for the mechanisms of the three SRS. Here, we introduce the price elasticity theory in economics to define sex ratio elasticity (SRE), and present an analytical model that derives three SRSs based on the following assumption: simultaneously existing competitions for both resources A and resources B influence the level of SRE in both sexes differently. Consequently, it is the difference (between two sexes) in the level of their sex ratio elasticity that leads to three different SRS. Our analytical results demonstrate that the elasticity-based model not only reveals a highly plausible mechanism that explains the evolution of SRS in nature, but also offers a novel framework for unifying two major classical theories (i.e., LMC & LRC) in the field of SRS research.

Collaboration


Dive into the Yaotang Li's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Rui-Wu Wang

Kunming Institute of Zoology

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

JunZhou He

Yunnan University of Finance and Economics

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Yaqiang Wang

Chinese Academy of Sciences

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Cheng-yi Zhang

Xi'an Jiaotong University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Lei Gao

Baoji University of Arts and Sciences

View shared research outputs
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge