Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where Ari Aisen is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by Ari Aisen.


European Journal of Political Economy | 2013

How does political instability affect economic growth

Ari Aisen; Francisco José Veiga

The purpose of this paper is to empirically determine the effects of political instability on economic growth. By using the system-GMM estimator for linear dynamic panel data models on a sample covering up to 169 countries, and 5-year periods from 1960 to 2004, we find that higher degrees of political instability are associated with lower growth rates of GDP per capita. Regarding the channels of transmission, we find that political instability adversely affects growth by lowering the rates of productivity growth and, to a smaller degree, physical and human capital accumulation. Finally, economic freedom and ethnic homogeneity are beneficial to growth, while democracy may have a small negative effect.


Documentos de Trabajo ( Banco Central de Chile ) | 2011

How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth

Ari Aisen; Francisco José Veiga

The purpose of this paper is to empirically determine the effects of political instability on economic growth. Using the system-GMM estimator for linear dynamic panel data models on a sample covering up to 169 countries, and 5-year periods from 1960 to 2004, we find that higher degrees of political instability are associated with lower growth rates of GDP per capita. Regarding the channels of transmission, we find that political instability adversely affects growth by lowering the rates of productivity growth and, to a smaller degree, physical and human capital accumulation. Finally, economic freedom and ethnic homogeneity are beneficial to growth, while democracy may have a small negative effect.


Applied Economics | 2008

Budget Deficits and Interest Rates: A Fresh Perspective

Ari Aisen; David Hauner

We extend the literature on budget deficits and interest rates in three ways: we examine both advanced and emerging economies and for the first time a large emerging market panel; explore interactions to explain some of the heterogeneity in the literature; and apply system GMM. There is overall a highly significant positive effect of budget deficits on interest rates, but the effect depends on interaction terms and is only significant under one of several conditions: deficits are high, mostly domestically financed, or interact with high domestic debt; financial openness is low; interest rates are liberalized; or financial depth is low.


Budget Deficits and Interest Rates : A Fresh Perspective | 2008

Budget Deficits and Interest Rates

Ari Aisen; David Hauner

for the first time in more than two decades. Indeed, mounting surpluses were projected for as far as the eye could see. But in 2002, as revenues began to flow into Washington more slowly and expenditures continued to rise, those black figures turned red. No one knows for sure, of course, when this will change. But it seems likely that federal budget deficits will be the norm for at least the near future. Changing fiscal conditions have reignited a debate among economists: Do budget deficits cause long-term interest rates to rise? Unfortunately, there is no consensus on this issue. “Despite a long history of analysis of fiscal policy, there is much less solidly based knowledge than one would like about the effects of government deficits on the economy,” notes Gerald Dwyer Jr. in an article in the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. For years, the conventional view was that government debt leads to increases in long-term interest rates, which decrease capital formulation, which ultimately leads to lower real income. How might public debt fuel higher long-term interest rates? The relationship “seems a trivial application of supply and demand,” Dwyer writes. “If the deficit increases, the supply of government bonds increases; everything else the same, the price of government bonds falls and the interest rate rises.” There is some evidence to support the claim that deficits do, in fact, raise long-term interest rates. In a recent paper, Thomas Laubach, an economist at the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors, wrote that the “estimated effects of government debt and deficits on interest rates are statistically and economically significant: a 1 percentage point increase in the projected deficit-to-GDP ratio is estimated to raise long-term interest rates by roughly 25 basis points.” But the positive correlation between budget deficits and higher long-term interest rates doesn’t always hold up under empirical testing. “There are three periods during which the federal deficit has exceeded 10 percent of national income. In none of these periods did interest rates rise appreciably. Regression analysis applied to data from these three periods has not uncovered a positive association between deficits and interest rates,” writes Paul Evans in a paper published in the American Economic Review. “There also appears to be no evidence for a positive association between deficits and interest rates during the postwar period. I conclude from this survey that the concerns of the popular press and many economists may be misplaced.” Likewise, Charles Plosser has been unable to find a positive correlation between public debt and higher interest rates in two papers for the Journal of Monetary Economics. The reason why some researchers have been unable to find such a correlation might be explained by the “Ricardian equivalence” theorem. This theorem is based on the notion that people are far-sighted and view deficits as simply postponed tax liabilities, which they will eventually have to pay. “The Ricardian equivalence theorem can account for the tenuousness of any relationship between government debt and the interest rate. Under certain conditions, an increase in the supply of government debt that is not acquired by the Federal Reserve and that finances a nondistortionary change in taxes does not affect the current and expected future opportunity sets of private agents,” writes Dwyer. “Hence, private agents’ current and expected future consumption are unchanged, the increase in private saving exactly equals the increase in the deficit, and the increase in the demand for government securities exactly equals the increase in the supply of government securities.” Robert Barro has become perhaps the leading proponent of the Ricardian equivalence theorem, first in a 1974 paper for the Journal of Political Economy and now in his textbook, Macroeconomics. None of this means that we should necessarily stop worrying about budget deficits. First, as Laubach’s paper demonstrates, the evidence isn’t as clear cut as proponents of the Ricardian equivalence theorem might claim. Second, even if budget deficits do not lead to higher interest rates, they are often the result of unwise government spending — spending that itself can produce distortions in the economy. Such spending should be avoided, no matter its effects on interest rates. In the end, the issue of whether it may be desirable, under certain circumstances, to run budget deficits involves more important questions than how those deficits will affect interest rates. It involves setting national priorities. For instance, we may, as a country, be willing to tolerate budget deficits in order to finance an important military campaign, as we did during World War II. Likewise, we may decide that it is desirable to run up some debt to pay the transition costs necessary to privatize the Social Security system. These are issues on which economics can shed some light. But they can’t be answered by economic analysis alone. RF B Y A A R O N S T E E L M A N LEGISLATIVEUPDATE


Social Science Research Network | 2004

Money-Based Versus Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization : Is There Space for Political Opportunism?

Ari Aisen

In response to high and chronic inflation, countries have adopted different stabilization policies. However, the extent to which these stabilization programs were designed for political motives is not clear. Since exchange-rate-based stabilizations (ERBS) create an initial consumption boom followed by a contraction, whereas money-based stabilizations (MBS) generate a consumption bust followed by a recovery, policymakers may consider the timing of elections when determining the nominal anchor for stabilization. This paper finds strong evidence that the choice of nominal anchor depends on elections, implying the existence of political opportunism. ERBS are, on average, launched before elections while MBS are set after them.


Panoeconomicus | 2007

Does Political Instability Lead to Higher and more Volatile Inflation? A Panel Data Analysis

Ari Aisen; Francisco José Veiga

Economists generally accept the proposition that high and volatile inflation rates generate inefficiencies that reduce societys welfare. Furthermore, studies have shown that inflation is harmful to economic growth. However, determining the causes of the worldwide diversity of inflationary experiences is an important challenge not yet satisfactorily confronted by the profession. Based on a broad dataset covering over 100 countries for the period 1975-1997 and using dynamic and static panel data econometric techniques, this paper shows that a higher degree of political instability is associated with both higher inflation levels and volatility. Not only does this paper advance the political economy literature establishing a relationship between inflation moments and political instability, but it also has important policy implications regarding the optimal design of inflation stabilization programs and of the institutions favorable to price stability.


Imf Staff Papers | 2007

Money-Based vs. Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization: Is There Room for Political Opportunism?

Ari Aisen

In response to high and chronic inflation, countries have adopted different stabilization policies. However, the extent to which these stabilization programs were designed for political motives is not clear. Because exchange-rate-based stabilizations (ERBS) create an initial consumption boom followed by a contraction, whereas money-based stabilizations generate a consumption bust followed by a recovery, policymakers may take into account the timing of elections when determining the nominal anchor for stabilization. This paper finds strong evidence that the choice of nominal anchor depends on elections, implying the existence of political opportunism. ERBS are, on average, launched before elections, whereas MBS are set after them.


Public Choice | 2006

Political Instability and Inflation Volatility

Ari Aisen; Francisco José Veiga


Journal Economía Chilena | 2010

Bank Credit During the 2008 Financial Crisis; A Cross-Country Comparison

Ari Aisen; Michael Franken


Journal of Development Economics | 2005

The political economy of seigniorage

Ari Aisen; Francisco José Veiga

Collaboration


Dive into the Ari Aisen's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

David Hauner

International Monetary Fund

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge