Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where Marie C. Thursby is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by Marie C. Thursby.


Management Science | 2002

Who Is Selling the Ivory Tower? Sources of Growth in University Licensing

Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

Historically, commercial use of university research has been viewed in terms of spillovers. Recently, there has been a dramatic increase in technology transfer through licensing as universities attempt to appropriate the returns from faculty research. This change has prompted concerns regarding the source of this growth-specifically, whether it suggests a change in the nature of university research. We develop an intermediate input model to examine the extent to which the growth in licensing is due to the productivity of observable inputs or driven by a change in the propensity of faculty and administrators to engage in commercializing university research. We model licensing as a three-stage process, each involving multiple inputs. Nonparametric programming techniques are applied to survey data from 64 universities to calculate total factor productivity (TFP) growth in each stage. To examine the sources of TFP growth, the productivity analysis is augmented by survey evidence from businesses who license-in university inventions. Results suggest that increased licensing is due primarily to an increased willingness of faculty and administrators to license and increased business reliance on external R&D rather than a shift in faculty research.


Journal of Technology Transfer | 2001

Objectives, Characteristics and Outcomes of University Licensing: A Survey of Major U.S. Universities

Jerry G. Thursby; Richard Jensen; Marie C. Thursby

This paper describes results of our survey of licensing at 62 research universities. We consider ownership, income splits, stage of development, marketing, license policies and characteristics, goals of licensing and the role of the inventor in licensing. Based on these results we analyze the relationship between licensing outcomes and both the objectives of the TTO and the characteristics of the technologies. Patent applications grow one-to-one with disclosures, while sponsored research grows similarly with licenses executed. Royalties are typically larger the higher the quality of the faculty and the higher the fraction of licenses that are executed at latter stages of development. Sponsored research is more likely to be included in a license if the new technology is at an early stage of development or if the TTO evaluates it as important. We find that additional disclosures generate smaller percentage increases in licenses, and those increases in licenses generate smaller percentage increases in royalties.


The Review of Economics and Statistics | 1987

Bilateral Trade Flows, the Linder Hypothesis, and Exchange Risk

Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

Bilateral trade flows are used to examine the Linder hypothesis and the effect of exchange-rate variability in a gra vity-type trade model derived from an underlying demand and supply mo del. A behavioral model is used to justify examining these issues joi ntly. The model performs well empirically using a sample of seventeen countries for the period 1974-82. The authors find overwhelming supp ort for the Linder hypothesis and this version of the gravity model. Moreover, they find strong support for the hypothesis that increased exchange-rate variability affects bilateral trade flows. Copyright 1987 by MIT Press.


International Journal of Industrial Organization | 2003

Disclosure and licensing of University inventions: `The best we can do with the s**t we get to work with¿

Richard Jensen; Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

Abstract We examine the interplay of the three major university actors in technology transfer from universities to industry: the faculty, the technology transfer office (TTO), and the central administration. We model the faculty as an agent of the administration, and the TTO as an agent of both the faculty and the administration. Empirical tests of the theory are based on evidence from our survey of 62 US research universities. We find that the TTOs reported licensing objectives are influenced by their views of faculty and administration, which supports the assumption that the TTO is a dual agent. The theory yields predictions for whether or not faculty disclose inventions and if so, at what stage, which in turn affects license contract terms. We also examine how the portion of inventions disclosed at different stages varies with faculty quality. Quality is found to be inversely related to the share of license income allotted to faculty.


Research Policy | 2009

US faculty patenting: Inside and outside the university

Jerry G. Thursby; Anne W. Fuller; Marie C. Thursby

This paper examines the empirical anomaly that in a sample of 5811 patents on which US faculty are listed as inventors, 26% of the patents are assigned solely to firms rather than to the faculty members university as is dictated by US university employment policies or the Bayh Dole Act. In this paper we estimate a series of probability models of assignment as a function of patent characteristics, university policy, and inventor fields in order to examine the extent to which outside assignment is nefarious or comes from legitimate activities, such as consulting. Patents assigned to firms (whether established or start-ups with inventor as principal) are less basic than those assigned to universities suggesting these patents result from faculty consulting. A higher inventor share increases the likelihood of university assignment as compared with assignment to a firm in which the inventor is a principal but it has no effect on consulting with established firms versus assignment to the university. Faculty in the physical sciences and engineering are more likely to assign their patents to established firms than those in biological sciences.


Contemporary Economic Policy | 2004

Are Faculty Critical? Their Role in University–Industry Licensing

Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

Understanding the nature of the involvement of faculty in university licensing is important for understanding how technology is transferred through licensing as well as more controversial issues, such as the need for university licensing. Using data from a survey of firms that actively license-in from universities we explore the importance of faculty in the licensing and development of inventions, as well as how and why they are used and how the use of faculty relates to characteristics of firms. In particular we find that the use of faculty through sponsored research in lieu of a license is closely related to the amount of basic research conducted by firms whereas the use of faculty within the terms of a license is related to the prevalence of personal contacts between industry R&D researchers and university faculty.


Management Science | 2008

Appropriability and Commercialization: Evidence from MIT Inventions

Emmanuel Dechenaux; Brent Goldfarb; Scott Shane; Marie C. Thursby

The effects of appropriability on invention have been well studied, but there has been little analysis of the effect of appropriability on the commercialization of existing inventions. Exploiting a database of 805 attempts by private firms to commercialize inventions licensed from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) between 1980 and 1996, we explore the influence of several appropriability mechanisms on the commercialization and termination of projects to develop products based on university inventions. Our central hypothesis is that the relationship between a licensees decision to either terminate or commercialize the invention is driven by the current market value of the invention, as well as the option value of delaying its commercialization. We use a competing risks framework that allows for nonparametric heterogeneity and correlated risks. We find that better appropriability in the sense of more effective patent strength and secrecy has a strong negative effect on the hazard of license termination. The effectiveness of learning has a strong positive effect on the hazard of technology commercialization, while lead time has a negative effect.


Industry and higher education | 2001

Industry Perspectives on Licensing University Technologies: Sources and Problems

Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

The authors report results of a survey of industry licensing executives who identified personal contacts between their R&D staff and university personnel as the most important source of university technologies. Journal publications and presentations at professional meetings were also important. While the least important sources were marketing efforts by universities and canvassing of universities, a number of executives did indicate that they were important. For those who do not license-in from universities, the most important reasons for not licensing-in (other than limited overall license-in activities) were reasons related to the nature of university research. A number cited university policies regarding delay of publication and ownership.


Journal of Technology Transfer | 2003

Industry/University Licensing: Characteristics, Concerns and Issues from the Perspective of the Buyer

Jerry G. Thursby; Marie C. Thursby

The authors previously explored invention licensing from the universitys perspective. In this paper we focus on the process from the perspective of firms activity engaged in licensing technology. A survey of industry licensing professionals addresses why some firms license technologies from universities and why others do not. The paper then considers the stage of development of university technologies, the characteristics of their licensing contracts, and sources of information about university technologies, all to better understand how the process works and what advantages and disadvantages it offers to all participants.


American Journal of Agricultural Economics | 1977

Devaluation, Foreign Trade Controls, and Domestic Wheat Prices

Paul R. Johnson; Thomas Grennes; Marie C. Thursby

The 1970s have seen sharp fluctuations in grain prices. Several plausible explanations for the unusual severity of these ups and downs have been advanced, including devaluation of the dollar for the upswing in 1972–74. U.S. wheat prices for the year of highest prices, 1973–74,are examined. A trade model that distinguishes wheat by country of origin is used to analyze various events in that year. It is concluded that insulating trade policies by wheat exporters and importers had the largest impact on U.S. wheat prices.

Collaboration


Dive into the Marie C. Thursby's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Jerry G. Thursby

Georgia Institute of Technology

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Richard Jensen

University of Notre Dame

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Kala Krishna

Pennsylvania State University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Anne W. Fuller

California State University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Frank T. Rothaermel

Georgia Institute of Technology

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Paul R. Johnson

North Carolina State University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Suddhasatwa Roy

California State University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Thomas Grennes

North Carolina State University

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Lin Jiang

University of Missouri

View shared research outputs
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge