Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where Yutaka Horita is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by Yutaka Horita.


Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America | 2009

The private rejection of unfair offers and emotional commitment

Toshio Yamagishi; Yutaka Horita; Haruto Takagishi; Mizuho Shinada; Shigehito Tanida; Karen S. Cook

In a series of experiments, we demonstrate that certain players of an economic game reject unfair offers even when this behavior increases rather than decreases inequity. A substantial proportion (30–40%, compared with 60–70% in the standard ultimatum game) of those who responded rejected unfair offers even when rejection reduced only their own earnings to 0, while not affecting the earnings of the person who proposed the unfair split (in an impunity game). Furthermore, even when the responders were not able to communicate their anger to the proposers by rejecting unfair offers in a private impunity game, a similar rate of rejection was observed. The rejection of unfair offers that increases inequity cannot be explained by the social preference for inequity aversion or reciprocity; however, it does provide support for the model of emotion as a commitment device. In this view, emotions such as anger or moral disgust lead people to disregard the immediate consequences of their behavior, committing them to behave consistently to preserve integrity and maintain a reputation over time as someone who is reliably committed to this behavior.


Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America | 2012

Rejection of unfair offers in the ultimatum game is no evidence of strong reciprocity

Toshio Yamagishi; Yutaka Horita; Nobuhiro Mifune; Hirofumi Hashimoto; Yang Li; Mizuho Shinada; Arisa Miura; Keigo Inukai; Haruto Takagishi; Dora Simunovic

The strong reciprocity model of the evolution of human cooperation has gained some acceptance, partly on the basis of support from experimental findings. The observation that unfair offers in the ultimatum game are frequently rejected constitutes an important piece of the experimental evidence for strong reciprocity. In the present study, we have challenged the idea that the rejection response in the ultimatum game provides evidence of the assumption held by strong reciprocity theorists that negative reciprocity observed in the ultimatum game is inseparably related to positive reciprocity as the two sides of a preference for fairness. The prediction of an inseparable relationship between positive and negative reciprocity was rejected on the basis of the results of a series of experiments that we conducted using the ultimatum game, the dictator game, the trust game, and the prisoner’s dilemma game. We did not find any correlation between the participants’ tendencies to reject unfair offers in the ultimatum game and their tendencies to exhibit various prosocial behaviors in the other games, including their inclinations to positively reciprocate in the trust game. The participants’ responses to postexperimental questions add support to the view that the rejection of unfair offers in the ultimatum game is a tacit strategy for avoiding the imposition of an inferior status.


PLOS Computational Biology | 2016

Reinforcement Learning Explains Conditional Cooperation and Its Moody Cousin.

Takahiro Ezaki; Yutaka Horita; Masanori Takezawa; Naoki Masuda

Direct reciprocity, or repeated interaction, is a main mechanism to sustain cooperation under social dilemmas involving two individuals. For larger groups and networks, which are probably more relevant to understanding and engineering our society, experiments employing repeated multiplayer social dilemma games have suggested that humans often show conditional cooperation behavior and its moody variant. Mechanisms underlying these behaviors largely remain unclear. Here we provide a proximate account for this behavior by showing that individuals adopting a type of reinforcement learning, called aspiration learning, phenomenologically behave as conditional cooperator. By definition, individuals are satisfied if and only if the obtained payoff is larger than a fixed aspiration level. They reinforce actions that have resulted in satisfactory outcomes and anti-reinforce those yielding unsatisfactory outcomes. The results obtained in the present study are general in that they explain extant experimental results obtained for both so-called moody and non-moody conditional cooperation, prisoner’s dilemma and public goods games, and well-mixed groups and networks. Different from the previous theory, individuals are assumed to have no access to information about what other individuals are doing such that they cannot explicitly use conditional cooperation rules. In this sense, myopic aspiration learning in which the unconditional propensity of cooperation is modulated in every discrete time step explains conditional behavior of humans. Aspiration learners showing (moody) conditional cooperation obeyed a noisy GRIM-like strategy. This is different from the Pavlov, a reinforcement learning strategy promoting mutual cooperation in two-player situations.


Scientific Reports | 2017

Reinforcement learning accounts for moody conditional cooperation behavior: experimental results.

Yutaka Horita; Masanori Takezawa; Keigo Inukai; Toshimasa Kita; Naoki Masuda

In social dilemma games, human participants often show conditional cooperation (CC) behavior or its variant called moody conditional cooperation (MCC), with which they basically tend to cooperate when many other peers have previously cooperated. Recent computational studies showed that CC and MCC behavioral patterns could be explained by reinforcement learning. In the present study, we use a repeated multiplayer prisoner’s dilemma game and the repeated public goods game played by human participants to examine whether MCC is observed across different types of game and the possibility that reinforcement learning explains observed behavior. We observed MCC behavior in both games, but the MCC that we observed was different from that observed in the past experiments. In the present study, whether or not a focal participant cooperated previously affected the overall level of cooperation, instead of changing the tendency of cooperation in response to cooperation of other participants in the previous time step. We found that, across different conditions, reinforcement learning models were approximately as accurate as a MCC model in describing the experimental results. Consistent with the previous computational studies, the present results suggest that reinforcement learning may be a major proximate mechanism governing MCC behavior.


Scientific Reports | 2016

Transient nature of cooperation by pay-it-forward reciprocity.

Yutaka Horita; Masanori Takezawa; Takuji Kinjo; Yo Nakawake; Naoki Masuda

Humans often forward kindness received from others to strangers, a phenomenon called the upstream or pay-it-forward indirect reciprocity. Some field observations and laboratory experiments found evidence of pay-it-forward reciprocity in which chains of cooperative acts persist in social dilemma situations. Theoretically, however, cooperation based on pay-it-forward reciprocity is not sustainable. We carried out laboratory experiments of a pay-it-forward indirect reciprocity game (i.e., chained gift-giving game) on a large scale in terms of group size and time. We found that cooperation consistent with pay-it-forward reciprocity occurred only in a first few decisions per participant and that cooperation originated from inherent pro-sociality of individuals. In contrast, the same groups of participants showed persisting chains of cooperation in a different indirect reciprocity game in which participants earned reputation by cooperating. Our experimental results suggest that pay-it-forward reciprocity is transient and disappears when a person makes decisions repeatedly, whereas the reputation-based reciprocity is stable in the same situation.


Evolution and Human Behavior | 2010

Emotional expressivity as a signal of cooperation

Joanna Schug; David Matsumoto; Yutaka Horita; Toshio Yamagishi; Kemberlee Bonnet


Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes | 2013

Is behavioral pro-sociality game-specific? Pro-social preference and expectations of pro-sociality

Toshio Yamagishi; Nobuhiro Mifune; Yang Li; Mizuho Shinada; Hirofumi Hashimoto; Yutaka Horita; Arisa Miura; Keigo Inukai; Shigehito Tanida; Toko Kiyonari; Haruto Takagishi; Dora Simunovic


Asian Journal of Social Psychology | 2012

Modesty in self-presentation: A comparison between the USA and Japan

Toshio Yamagishi; Hirofumi Hashimoto; Karen S. Cook; Toko Kiyonari; Mizuho Shinada; Nobuhiro Mifune; Keigo Inukai; Haruto Takagishi; Yutaka Horita; Yang Li


Neuro endocrinology letters | 2010

Stress hormones predict hyperbolic time-discount rates six months later in adults

Taiki Takahashi; Mizuho Shinada; Keigo Inukai; Shigehito Tanida; Chisato Takahashi; Nobuhiro Mifune; Haruto Takagishi; Yutaka Horita; Hirofumi Hashimoto; Kunihiro Yokota; Tatsuya Kameda; Toshio Yamagishi


Letters on Evolutionary Behavioral Science | 2010

Punishers May Be Chosen as Providers But Not as Recipients

Yutaka Horita

Collaboration


Dive into the Yutaka Horita's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Nobuhiro Mifune

Kochi University of Technology

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge