Network


Latest external collaboration on country level. Dive into details by clicking on the dots.

Hotspot


Dive into the research topics where Christopher Hanes is active.

Publication


Featured researches published by Christopher Hanes.


The Journal of Economic History | 1996

Changes in the Cyclical Behavior of Real Wage Rates, 1870–1990

Christopher Hanes

A modern households consumption bundle is more finished than that of a typical worker in the past: the average consumption good passes through more stages of production before purchase. This has affected the cyclical behavior of wages relative to the price of the consumption bundle because wages are more procyclical relative to prices of more-finished goods. Nowadays real consumption wages are procyclical. They were less procyclical before the Second World War, and they may have been acyclical or even countercyclical before the First World War.


Journal of Money, Credit and Banking | 1999

Degrees of Processing and Changes in the Cyclical Behavior of Prices in the United States, 1869-1990

Christopher Hanes

Price indices for periods before the Second World War place more weight on less-processed products than do their postwar counterparts to an extent that exaggerates the change over time in the composition of aggregate output. Prices of less-processed products are especially procyclical in levels and inflation rates. Thus, comparisons between historical and postwar series can give biased measures of changes in the cyclical behavior of the aggregate price level. Also, changes in the behavior of the aggregate price level must be distinguished from changes in the behavior of prices of given products, subject to a given degree of processing.


The Journal of Economic History | 2013

Harvests and Financial Crises in Gold-Standard America

Christopher Hanes; Paul W. Rhode

Most American financial crises of the postbellum gold-standard era were caused by fluctuations in the cotton harvest due to exogenous factors such as weather. The transmission channel ran through export revenues and financial markets under the pre-1914 monetary regime. A poor cotton harvest depressed export revenues and reduced international demand for American assets, which depressed American stock prices, drained deposits from money-center banks and precipitated a business-cycle downturn - conditions that bred financial crises. The crises caused by cotton harvests could have been prevented by an American central bank, even under gold-standard constraints.


The American Economic Review | 2003

Wage Adjustment Under Low Inflation: Evidence from U.S. History

Christopher Hanes; John A. James

Data from recent years indicate that employers are especially unlikely to cut the nominal wage rate paid for a job. Adjustments to real or relative wages that require absolute cuts in money wages are very rare, relative to the frequency one might expect to observe based on distributions of wage changes that do not require money wage cuts (Erica L. Groshen and Mark E. Schweitzer, 1995, 1997; David E. Lebow et al., 1999). A worker who remains with the same employer from one year to the next is accordingly unlikely to report an absolute reduction in the nominal wage he receives (David Card and Dean Hyslop, 1997; Shulamit Kahn, 1997; Joseph G. Altonji and Paul J. Devereux, 1999). The existence and causes of “downward nominal wage rigidity” have implications for macroeconomic outcomes and for practical issues in monetary policy. Presumably, efficient operation of labor markets requires many downward adjustments of relative wages, and occasional decreases in the overall wage level relative to product prices. If the average rate of wage inflation were close to zero, some of these relative or real wage adjustments would be blocked by a floor under current levels of nominal wage rates. George A. Akerlof et al. (1996) assert that downward nominal wage rigidity reflects fundamental preferences of workers, and argue that it implies a central bank should target a rate of price inflation greater than zero because “a target of zero inflation will impose permanent real costs on the economy” (p. 2). The notion that downward nominal wage rigidity is a fundamental constraint, so that inflation serves to “grease the wheels of the labor market,” is controversial even among those who accept the possibility of nominal rigidities in general. It has been argued that downward nominal wage rigidity, as distinct from such phenomena as “menu costs” [which would discourage adjustment of a wage in either direction (David Romer, 1993)], may be an artifact of an inflationary monetary regime, and would disappear in the absence of persistent inflation. “Nominal wage reductions would no longer be seen as unusual if the average nominal wage was not growing. Workers would not see them as unfair, and firms would not shy away from imposing them” (Robert J. Gordon, 1996, p. 62; see also N. Gregory Mankiw, 1996; William Poole, 1998; William B. English, 2000). To see whether downward nominal wage rigidity would exist in a noninflationary regime, it may be useful to examine data from times and places where there was no persistent wage inflation. For the United States, at least, that excludes data from years since the Second World War: throughout the postwar period, price inflation or real wage growth has been sufficient to keep average wage inflation above zero. Before the Second World War, on the other hand, long-run trend rates of price inflation were often close to zero or negative (Robert B. Barsky, 1987). If wage inflation was correspondingly low, U.S. historical data may offer tests of the proposition that downward nominal wage rigidity exists even in noninflationary


The Journal of Economic History | 1996

Turnover Cost and the Distribution of slave Labor in Anglo-America

Christopher Hanes

In the eighteenth-century British Empire and the antebellum South, slaves were concentrated in domestic service and rural enterprises like agriculture and ironworks. I argue that employers in these sectors chose to employ slaves rather than free labor because they faced especially high turnover costs—that is, costs of searching for a worker and going without labor when a free worker quit or was fired. In the absence of slavery, these sectors were marked by other institutions designed to deal with turnover costs: indentured servitude, employment agencies, and deferred compensation.


The American Economic Review | 1993

The Development of Nominal Wage Rigidity in the Late 19th Century

Christopher Hanes


The American Economic Review | 2000

Nominal Wage Rigidity and Industry Characteristics in the Downturns of 1893, 1929, and 1981

Christopher Hanes


Quarterly Journal of Economics | 2009

Harvests and Business Cycles in Nineteenth-Century America

Joseph H. Davis; Christopher Hanes; Paul W. Rhode


Journal of Money, Credit and Banking | 2006

The Liquidity Trap and U.S. Interest Rates in the 1930s

Christopher Hanes


Explorations in Economic History | 1996

Immigrants' Relative Rate of Wage Growth in the Late 19th Century

Christopher Hanes

Collaboration


Dive into the Christopher Hanes's collaboration.

Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Paul W. Rhode

National Bureau of Economic Research

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Charles W. Calomiris

National Bureau of Economic Research

View shared research outputs
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar
Top Co-Authors

Avatar

Mark Thomas

University of Virginia

View shared research outputs
Researchain Logo
Decentralizing Knowledge